Cross Subsidizing in Russia’s Power Industry

Main page


The article and the slides on “Cross Subsidizing in Russia’s Power Industry” show the results of an analytical study of cities’ heat power cogeneration systems. The analysis results show the climatic affect on the generation of power policy. Russian Power Industry’s scarce market experience, poor state policy concerning efficient power saving, inefficient antimonopoly legislation and availability of cheap fuel in combination with huge cross-subsidizing in Heat Power and Electricity-generating Industries are the basis of careless attitude to power related issues in the society. The material covers proposals to be included in Russia’s Federal and Regional fuel-saving programs aimed at reducing the loss down to 7÷66% of fuel consumed in the course of heat and electricity cogeneration in a cogeneration plant.

 

______________________________________________________________________________________________

 

“THE USE OF BOILER HOUSES IS RUSSIA’S NATIONAL DISASTER” part 8

Cross Subsidizing in Russia’s Power Industry

A.Bogdanov  

Omsk Electricity-generating Company Perspective Development Department Head Deputy. 

 Heat Power Industry Analyst.

 

 

Slides

 

Where is the root of all evil? Why are the methods that in terms of technological and business indicators ensure benefit of up to 40% of fuel NOT used in Russia? The problem is concerned with efficient and adequate estimation of costs spent on generating heat power and electric Power, Capacity and Margin. In case of energy generation combined cycle the review of costs that determine the value of tariffs for various energy goods and services: Power, Capacity and Margin is presented in my articles: “The Use of Boiler Houses is Russia’s National Disaster” published in the EnergyMarket1 and Heat Supply News2 Journals; besides, the articles are available at:  www.exergy.narod.ru

The main source of all these troubles in the Heat Power Industry of Russia is the lack of marketing aimed at the promotion of energy goods and services which, in its turn, leads to cross subsidizing in the Power-generating Industry. While there is some minor progress in the Electricity-generating Industry, for instance, the creation of The New Wholesale Market of Critical Power and Energy (NWMCPE), the marketing of heat energy and power, to say nothing of combined-cycle energy, sees neither attempts to understand the current situation nor even interest to make such attempts.

 

Taking into account the lack of market experience for the Heat Power Industry and the lack of special knowledge concerning combined-cycle energy generation cost estimation when it is required to ensure various types of power margin, experts of Russia’s Power Industry Regulatory Bodies are incapable of seeing the current problematic situation in Russia’s Power-generating Industry as one complex whole.

 

Extracts from classical works

    Extracts from the article “he Deregulation of the Electricity Industry. A Primer.” by Peter M. VanDoren[1]

Cross Subsidies  

*Very few residential customers of electric utilities currently face real-time marginal-cost prices. Instead they face average costs that vary at most twice a year between winter and summer. In a completely deregulated market, consumers would presumably face lower off-peak prices and higher peak prices. That, in turn, might create political pressure to protect residential consumers from "too high" peak prices. States facing such pressure might mandate that residential customers be offered an average-pricing plan. Public utilities' costs do not differ substantially from those of private utilities, but they price their output differently. As one would expect of a firm driven by electoral concerns, publicly owned utilities have lower residential and higher industrial electric prices than do investor-owned utilities. The possibility of policy change always results in opposition from those who perceive that they will lose market privileges that they currently posses as well as from those who do not think that their share of future benefits will be appropriate. Electricity is no exception to that rule. Those who are subsidized in the current regime worry about the loss of subsidies if deregulation occurs.

Cross subsidies exist if some customers are charged prices that are above marginal cost in order to allow

other customers to be charged less than marginal cost. Cross subsidies are possible under monopoly because the "taxed" consumers may not choose an alternative supplier who charges them less. Cross subsidies are not sustainable in competitive markets because the "taxed" customers may choose an alternative supplier who does not "tax" them. The good news is that cross subsidies are not viable in deregulated markets. Cross subsidies distort prices and serve equity goals very imperfectly.

Means-tested vouchers for individuals can serve equity goals better with fewer price distortions. Subsidies in the form of vouchers are more compatible with market innovations. If conventional electric service to rural areas was expensive when correctly priced and the political system responded with means-tested rural-electric vouchers, recipients might buy microturbines with their subsidy to save some of the money they spend on correctly priced, expensive, conventional electric service.

Vouchers would be subject to much more public scrutiny. By contrast, cross subsidies are embedded invisibly within existing rates in ways that voters do not perceive. Under closer public scrutiny, many cross subsidies would not survive. Annual, transparent, sliding-scale voucher subsidies are more compatible with markets than are cross subsidies. To be sure, the rationales for these subsidies (with perhaps the exception of the low-income program) will not survive close public scrutiny, but if they do, explicit congressional or state appropriations are more efficient than invisible cross subsidies that alter the price of electricity at the margin. Rather than use brute force to separate generation from transmission and distribution and regulate the grid as a common carrier, why not just eliminate federal and state regulation of the existing vertically integrated utilities and let market forces discover the "best" economic arrangements?

                 (The full text of the article in the Russian language is presented at: www.libertarium.ru/ libertarium/der_energy05)

 

“...Unfortunately RAO UES of Russia (Unified Energy System of the Russian Federation) being the monopolist does not find it necessity of any further electricity market research[2]

 

 

 

  10 Types of Cross Subsidizing in the Region’s Economy

As a result of the lack of efficient heat and electricity Power, Capacity and Margin marketing, to say nothing of the combined cycle energy and power, Russia’s current tariff policy has led to launch a very deep-set invisible (technology-based) and visible (social) cross subsidizing in the Power-generating Industry. The Regulatory Bodies – Federal Tariffs Service and Regional Energy Committee – have come to firmly believe that it is not economically beneficial to use condensing cycle with cogeneration plants. On the other hand the cost analysis carried out based upon the demand for fuel required to generate and transport electricity and heat power shows a different situation. Figure 1 shows energy loss streams as fuel loss that takes place in the course of electricity generation and transportation from cogeneration plants and electricity-generating stations. It is plainly visible that economic indicators for both electricity-generating and cogeneration plants’ condensing-cycle electricity production and shipment are equal. Taking into account the fuel loss that takes place during electricity transportation to the end user the fuel loss is as follows: а) for electricity delivered from a distant electricity-generating station: at least 62÷64%, b) for condensing cycle electricity produced at a cogeneration plant close to the consumer: at least 64÷65%.

It is clearly seen that even with this fuel loss the electricity produced according to the cogen cycle costs the society 4 times less than the electricity produced according to the condensing cycle (15% vs 64%)!

 

Type 1

Subsidizing of electricity generation at the expense of heat power produced at the cogeneration plant

Electricity subsidizing at the expense of heat power. This is the most widespread type of subsidizing used at cogeneration plants and debated about since 1952. The subsidizing of electricity generation at the expense of heat power reaches up to 30 % of fuel and related overheads distributed in proportion to the fuel that is presumably required for the generating of electricity. This type of subsidizing is discussed in detail in my articles published in previous issues of the journals (“The Use of Boiler House …” parts 2-3). This type of subsidizing also includes some cost transfer methods, such as manufacturer’s cross subsidizing between basic, semi-basic and on-peak heat power and electricity.

 

 

Type 2

 

Subsidizing of electricity consumers at the expense of cogeneration plant’s heat power consumers

 

Subsidizing of electricity consumers at the expense of the consumers receiving heat power from the cogeneration plant. This method of cross subsidizing is invisible and absolutely hidden from ordinary consumers. In order to understand this method one must clearly understand cost-generating mechanisms connected with the consumption of combined energy received from the cogeneration plant. From the times of the USSR to the present day there has been a widespread opinion that heat power generation at the cogeneration plant is economically unprofitable and the state is forced to provide donations for the production of heat power by the cogeneration plants at the expense of electricity which is more profitable. Presently regional energy committees proclaim privileged tariffs for the population. Still this opinion is deeply wrong. Heat power calculations of primary fuel costs stipulated in the current norm-setting documents made without any political pressure or cross subsidizing show that each consumer using the heat power produced thanks to the cogeneration plant’s spent steam is a very beneficial consumer providing 28-50% of fuel not only for him/herself but also for electricity consumers who do not use heat from the cogeneration plant. It is the fact that the country’s cold climate leads to the consumption of heat power 10-12 times exceeding the consumption of electricity (figure 2) that is the basic indicator proving that city and town residents receiving heat power from the cogeneration plant provide low-price electricity not only for themselves but also for other residents of the region. Up to the present there are no such notions of power consumers as “donor” and “careless user”. Thus, a budgeted consumer such as, for instance, a kindergarten, a school or a social, a medical institution, a city resident consuming electricity from a cogeneration plant do not belong to the category in need of subsidies but on the contrary – are “power saving donors” who subsidize other consumers that do not use cogeneration plant heat power.

 

 

 

 

     

 

Type 3

Subsidizing of electricity supply Capacity (reliability) at the expense of energy fees

Subsidizing of electricity generating capacity maintenance costs at the expense electricity costs. This is the most widespread type of cross-subsidizing used at the stage of electricity shipment. It is used in the estimation of services of electric network companies, system operator, sales network operator. Fees for the margin, for the required reliability and failure-free supply of electricity – are hard-to-measure categories which require a detailed analysis. Real costs required to ensure capacity Margin may amount to at least 50-300% of the costs required to ensure on-balance capacity. Nevertheless, due to the lack of methodology for estimating Margin, System Reliability and Failure-free Operation related costs they are not specified as a separate service but are included in the Power and Capacity fees as an extra fee in the form of cross subsidizing for the purpose of calculation simplification.

At the stage of electricity shipment and distribution energy-related variable costs that are determined based upon electricity loss resulting from idle running and warming-up (reflected as primary fuel loss) are not the key costs and amount to no more than 20% of energy producer’s costs. The key costs for a shipment company are the capacity maintenance costs classified based upon the process characteristic: on-balance electricity power; off-balance “stand-by capacity”, off-balance “seasonal” power capacity; off-peak on-balance capacity required to attract off-peak summer consumers; “proclaimed perspective” capacity of the coming years, “long-term ownerless” power capacity not declared by the consumer etc. (Classification of types of energy services is presented in my article “The Use of Boiler Houses…”, part 4).  A special type of cross subsidizing in the Electricity-generating Industry used to be a user’s fee intended to cover system reliability assurance and federal network construction costs. 

Transfer from invisible to visible subsidizing will enable one to determine the cost of such types of energy services: fee for short-term and long-term electric power capacity, fee for non-justified “ownerless” capacity, fee for energy-saving category – 1, 2, 3 etc. The current consumer will either be willing to pay the costs related to the aforementioned items or the electricity network owner will have to cover the costs. The desire to assign capacity and electrical power maintenance costs to the energy price leads to hiding these expenses and as well as to the lack of incentives to identify, norm-set and gradually decrease them.

 

Type 4

Subsidizing of Capacity, heat supply Margin Capacity at the expense of Energy fees

            Subsidizing of heat-generating capacities maintenance costs, heat capacity margin costs at the expense of heat power generation costs. This is also a very widespread type of cross subsidizing in the Power Industry which is based upon the lack of methodology-based approach to the estimation of costs required to ensure reliable and failure-free heat supply. The costs required to ensure reliable heat supply are one of the highest costs that amount to at least 30-150% of the power costs; besides these costs are the least studied costs in terms of norm-setting. One of the reasons that this type of subsidizing exists is that the system enabling to measure heat power per external air calculated temperature is still poorly developed. Until now calculations and norm-setting practice do not account for such notions as network pipe installed capacity, network pipe actual capacity, pipe’s calculated annual throughput, network pipe’s actual energy and power annual throughput. The existing methodology does not use such notions as: calculation of costs required to ensure low-potential (up to 70°С) heat power and high-potential (above 115°С) heat power. In the Heat Power Industry the situation concerning the identification of heat generating capacity margin maintenance costs is even worse than in the Electricity-generating Industry. There is no power cost classification or norm-setting system:  а) based upon the process characteristic, b) on-balance heat power; с) off-balance “stand-by capacity”; d) off-balance “seasonal” power capacity; е) off-peak “on-balance” power necessary to attract off-peak summer consumers; “proclaimed perspective” power capacity of the coming years; “long-term ownerless” power capacity not specified by the consumer etc.

            The exclusion of reliability assurance costs or reliability assurance through non-economic measures – namely, by means of assigning the costs to other expense items leads to the distortion of heat energy and power real costs.

 

Types 5 and 6. Subsidizing of social consumers (electorate).  “Everyone at everyone’s expense”

            Social (visible) subsidizing of various types of consumers in favor of the population. What is interesting is that the basis of this type of subsidizing is not process-related but social differences that determine electorate’s behavior. The population is subsided at the expense of industries and commercial consumers. This type of subsidizing is used both in the visible form at the tariffs generating stage and in the invisible or semi-invisible form. A good example of semi-visible social subsidizing is different natural gas tariffs. For instance, the population and public utilities services are offered privileged or so-called limited gas tariffs while industrial consumers are faced with “above-the-limit” gas tariffs exceeding those for thee population by 30-40%.

 

Types 7 and 8

Subsidizing of distant consumers at the expense of close consumers

            Subsidizing of distant consumers at the expense of close consumers is one of the most widespread and relatively “innocent” types of cross subsidizing used in the current tariffs regulating practice. For instance, in the Electricity-generating Industry this method is used to subsidize distant villages, elite areas and resort territories located at about 15-30 km away from electricity sources and whose load is around 10÷15 lamps. In the Heat Power Industry, for instance, this method is used to subsidize detached houses built away from main heat lines. The most widespread form of cross subsidizing is artificial unification of various sources into a unified power center, the joining of inefficient and efficient heat power sources.

           

Type 9 “Time-based” subsidizing of new consumers at the expense of old consumers

This is the most widespread, the most invisible and the least discussed type of cross subsidizing in the Power Generating Industry. The subsidizing of current time new consumers’ costs at the expense of old consumers. This type of subsidizing is widely used when new consumers are connected to the existing electricity or heating systems.

 

Type 10 Subsidizing of new technologies, power saving, “green” technologies

Producers of “green” energy and power using environmental-friendly power-saving technologies: waste incineration plants, heat pumps, heat batteries etc.

 


“Inconsistent” electricity and heat power supply policy in the regions

Inconsistent policy – contradictions arising between words (proclamations of politicians) and actions (actual measures implemented)[3]. Cross subsidizing is good for managers of large electricity-generating companies that use the flaws of regulations and recommendations in favor of Electricity-generating Industry. The desire of large energy generating companies to use company-average or holding-average calculations is quite understandable. When companies on the on hand are presumably in the market conditions and on the other hand they are still regulated structures, they can afford not to work on real cost minimization. Cross subsidizing is good for politicians, town or city mayors, region governors who are forced to make decisions contradicting their previously declared obligations to decrease energy tariffs. It is much simpler to work with the electorate - heat and electricity consumers paying equal prices than explain why real costs for consumers from a street powered from a cogeneration plant are 2÷5 times lower than for consumers residing in a street powered from a residual fuel-operated boiler house. 

But neither the Federal Law “On Electricity-generating Industry”, nor the Draft of the Federal Law “On Heat Supply” responds to the following questions: what does one do with huge unused capacities of power generating sources, power transmission lines, main and district heat lines? Who is going to cover the maintenance cost spent on the equipment with long-term (over 2 years) power margin of over 4 %? Should it be the consumer who pays long-term capacity margin costs or should it be the owner who has a huge power margin and no real perspective of demand growth?

A few more words about cross subsidizing

“..another problem arising as a result of the “average costs plus profit” pricing model is brought to light by the notion “cross subsidizing”. In itself cross subsidizing is a form of price discrimination, in other words it enables one to fix such price level that covers average common costs of the industry. In this case some consumers pay higher prices than the value of the goods and services they receive while some consumers pay lower prices[4]”.

 (page 394)…….for a number of reasons the regulation of natural monopolies based upon the profit rate they receive is not always a success. This good idea is often undermined by such an unpleasant motif as political rent seeking. Hypothetically there are two possibilities: merging of entrepreneurship and supervisory bodies and consequent filling of the positions with interested persons or bribers and patience of supervisory bodies in relation to some companies where state bureaucrats and politicians hope to “seek shelter” after their time in office is over. There is also another threat: in some fields supervisory bodies are under very severe pressing from consumers who are interested to minimize the prices ignoring long-term demands and needs of businesses and industries.  

Another important problem is the lack of knowledge concerning real profit rates in various industries. Accurate measurement of a company or a business capital, actual market-based profit rate and alternative value of invested capital seems to be an overcomplicated task. The more guesswork and “out-of-the blue” data, the higher the probability of erroneous and careless decisions.

Last but not least. If a company is placed within the framework of the “costs plus profit” model the regulation of the market process undermines the basic incentives of market economy. If company’s profit exceeds the costs by a certain value, it eliminates the necessity to minimize the costs which is rather complicated to do. Thus, the incentives to minimize the costs are weakened.

As was mentioned earlier, it is quite probable that natural monopoly regulation efficiency calculations use increased (or decreased) profit rates per capital that may not match the alternative value of its use. For instance, in the 50÷60s the profit rates in the Electricity Supply and Power Industries were very much increased which easily attracted the capital to the construction of new power stations (which, by the way, later became part of industry’s basic estimation calculations). That led to careless and overabundant investment into the Industry. In the 80s the situation changed – the profit rates were decreased. It led to the decrease in investment required for normal operation of the Industry. Moreover, low prices for such services disguise the acuteness of the problem. In the course of equipment aging and depreciation the quality of electricity supply services rendered to the population sharply drops; some experts predict a serious deficit of electricity in case of using an artificial profit rate suppression mechanism in the Industry. Thus, profit-rate artificial regulation mechanism gives a two-edged effect while the efficiency of the market process is caught in the narrow pathway between two extremes.

(page 395)It is a priori believed that electricity generation maximum costs are constant and only slightly different from the common average costs taking into account the product yield.  It is easy to prove that in practice such view is rather idealistic (for instance, power plant commissioning time brings about a change of maximum costs for new and outdated power-generating stations). Thus, Regulatory Bodies have to differentiate their pricing policy within one Industry which may result in the prices below the maximum cost level, lack of incentives to implement modern resource-saving technologies etc.

 

 

Measures in tended to eliminate cross subsidizing in the Heat Generating Industry of Russia.

At the Federal Level:

  1. Stipulate in the Law the responsibility of the Federal Bodies (Ministry of Economic Affairs, Ministry of Industry and Power, Ministry of Natural Resources etc.) concerning efficient use of fuel in Russia;
  2. Develop the “Power Code of the Russian Federation” that is to include articles from the Laws “On Electricity-generating Industry”, “On Power Saving” and from the Draft of the Law “On Heat Supply”;
  3. Develop the National Project: “State-initiated Cogeneration Development in Russia”;
  4. Develop “Recommendations on Identification of Power-saving Effect” and extend “6tp” statistics with “Fuel Saving Potential through Power Cogeneration” Section;
  5. Develop “Recommendations on Identification of Visible and Invisible Cross Subsidizing Scope” in the Heat Generating Industry of Russia.

At the Regional Level:

  1. Specify a Body responsible for the efficient use of fuel in the Region;
  2. Approve and implement “Regulations on the Generating of Heat Supply Systems and Public Utilities Companies’ Integrated Development”;
  3. Develop a long-term “Program on Stage-by-stage Transfer from Quality to Quantity-based Regulation of Heat Delivery to Public Utilities Consumers”;
  4. Implement “The Regional Standard of Heat and Cogen Power Consumption”;
  5. Develop and implement “City Complex Heat and Power Facility Operation Quality Estimation System”.

 

                                                                                                                      Alexander Bogdanov

 

 



[5][1] Peter M. VanDoren  “The Deregulation of the Electricity Industry. A Primer.”. Russian edition is available at: www.libertarium.ru/ libertarium/der_energy05)

* Here and further in the text bold, red, underlined and italicized text is according to Mr. Bogdanov (translator’s remark)

[6][2] Marketing / U. Rudelius and others  -M: DeNovo, 2001-706 pages, page 342

[7][3] N.Gregory Mankiw ‘Principles of Macroeconomics’ – quoted by Russian editions, 2nd edition, PITER 2006, page # 536

[8][4] Edwin J. Dollan; David E. Lidsney “The Market. Microeconomic Model” - quoted by Russian editions, translated from the English language by V. Lukashevich and colleagues, edited by  B. Lisovik and V. Lukashevich. moscow.1996, 496pages

 

 

Slides




[1] Peter M. VanDoren  “The Deregulation of the Electricity Industry. A Primer.”. Russian edition is available at: www.libertarium.ru/ libertarium/der_energy05)

* Here and further in the text bold, red, underlined and italicized text is according to Mr. Bogdanov (translator’s remark)

[2] Marketing / U. Rudelius and others  -M: DeNovo, 2001-706 pages, page 342

[3] N.Gregory Mankiw ‘Principles of Macroeconomics’ – quoted by Russian editions, 2nd edition, PITER 2006, page # 536

[4] Edwin J. Dollan; David E. Lidsney “The Market. Microeconomic Model” - quoted by Russian editions, translated from the English language by V. Lukashevich and colleagues, edited by  B. Lisovik and V. Lukashevich. moscow.1996, 496pages